US President Donald Trump’s 2025 executive order on Reciprocal Tariffs marks a dramatic shift in U.S. trade policy, imposing broad new duties on imports in the name of fairness and national security.
For much of the 19th and early 20th centuries, high tariffs were a cornerstone of U.S. economic policy. In an era when the United States was still industrializing (and before income taxes existed), import duties served both to raise government revenue and protect nascent industries. In fact, in some years during the 19th century, tariffs provided as much as 95% of federal revenue. Protectionism, the concept of shielding developing domestic industries (‘infant industries’) from larger foreign competitors, is not new. It helped the US transition from a small agrarian economy to a global industrial powerhouse. By the late 19th century, the U.S. had become a net creditor nation with trade surpluses, and tariffs were viewed as a tool to keep foreign competition at bay while American factories expanded. However, these policies were not without consequences: trading partners often retaliated in kind, and consumers faced higher prices.
The infamous Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act of 1930 raised U.S. import tariffs to nearly 60% on average – one of the highest levels in U.S. history. This broad-based hike, enacted as the U.S. was a creditor nation trying to shield itself during the onset of the Great Depression, triggered a spiral of global retaliation. Dozens of countries, including Canada and European nations, retaliated with their own tariffs, hurting US exporters (especially farmers) and deepening the collapse of world trade. History widely regards Smoot-Hawley as a policy that exacerbated the Depression by igniting trade wars and collapsing international commerce. Crucially, these events taught U.S. policymakers that blanket tariff hikes could be self-defeating.
In response, the U.S. radically shifted course with the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act of 1934 (RTAA). Under the RTAA and subsequent U.S. leadership in creating a multilateral trading system, tariffs steadily came down. From 1934 to 1945, the U.S. signed 32 bilateral agreements to reciprocally reduce tariffs, and after 1947 the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) facilitated eight multilateral negotiating rounds through 1994 that slashed tariffs globally. This established the modern principle of trade reciprocity through mutual reduction – a pillar of the post-war order. The United States emerged from World War II as the world’s preeminent economy and a champion of free trade, maintaining relatively low tariffs to promote an open, US-led global trading system. By the late 20th century, U.S. tariffs averaged well under 10%, and trade policy focused on creating institutions like the WTO (1995) to lock in rules against the kinds of protectionist escalation seen in the 1930s.
The contemporary context (2020s) finds the U.S. in a very different position than in the 1890s or 1930s. Today, the United States is a large debtor nation running persistent trade and current account deficits, and its economy is dominated by services rather than manufacturing. Government revenue is now largely drawn from income and payroll taxes, not tariffs – in fiscal year 2024 the U.S. collected about $4 trillion from income taxes versus only ~$76 billion from customs duties. Tariffs today account for under 2% of federal revenue, compared to up to half of revenue in the late 1800s. U.S. import tariffs are also at historic lows by past standards. Prior to 2025, the simple average U.S. MFN1 tariff was about 3.3–3.4% – among the lowest in the world – reflecting 75 years of trade liberalization. Major emerging partners have higher average tariffs (e.g. the EU ~5%, China ~7.5%, India ~17% on average). The U.S. has complained that this disparity puts its producers at a disadvantage, but it has traditionally pursued redress through negotiation or targeted trade cases rather than across-the-board tariff hikes.
In short, the US historically used high tariffs as a developing industrial nation. As a mature economy leading a global system however, it embraced low tariffs and multilateral rules. President Trump’s new reciprocal tariff policy essentially seeks to turn back the clock to an earlier trade posture – but under very different economic circumstances than the past.
The 2025 “Reciprocal Tariff Policy” Executive Order: Key Features
Trump’s 2025 executive order represents a sweeping assertion of tariff authority in an effort to “rebalance” trade relationships. In Trump’s view, decades of U.S. openness coupled with other countries’ higher tariffs and non-tariff barriers have “hollowed out” American manufacturing and even undermined the defense industrial base.
Core provisions
Effective April 5, 2025, the U.S. imposes a baseline 10% ad valorem tariff on all imports from all countries (with only narrow exceptions). This is essentially a global tariff surcharge applied on top of any existing duties. Then, starting April 9, 2025, higher country-specific tariff rates kick in for dozens of nations that the administration deems to have especially non-reciprocal trade practices (generally those with high tariffs or big trade surpluses with the US).
These “reciprocal tariffs” vary by country. For example, the European Union faces a 20% U.S. tariff, Japan 24%, South Korea 25%, India 26%, Thailand 36%, Taiwan 32%, and Vietnam a steep 46%. China, which the U.S. cites as having the largest bilateral trade imbalance ($295 billion goods surplus in 2024), is hit with a 34% U.S. tariff. (Notably, because the Trump administration had already imposed separate 20% tariffs on Chinese goods in February 2025 over the fentanyl crisis, the effective tariff on China’s exports reaches about 54% in total. By contrast, some countries that do not run surpluses with the U.S. or are viewed as having more open markets remain at the baseline 10%. For instance, Brazil, the UK, and Singapore – each of which actually ran trade deficits with the U.S. in 2024 – are kept at 10%. (White House officials argued that many of these countries would run surpluses if their policies weren’t already relatively fair). In a striking omission, Russia was not assigned a higher rate despite its $2.5 billion goods surplus with the U.S. This is likely due to existing sanctions that have curtailed trade to the country.
The policy’s design tries to account for certain exemptions and special cases: Goods from Canada and Mexico – traditional close partners – are technically subject to these tariffs, but many are effectively exempt due to parallel actions. Any Canadian or Mexican goods that qualify as originating under USMCA (the free trade agreement) continue to enter tariff-free. This carve-out for USMCA-origin goods “will continue indefinitely,” sparing North American supply chains for auto manufacturers and others from immediate disruption.
Additionally, a rule was included to soften impact on complex supply chains: if an imported article contains at least 20% U.S.-made content, the extra tariff applies only to the foreign value-added portion. This is an unusual, complicated mechanism directing Customs to assess the U.S. content in imports so as not to penalize American-made components incorporated abroad. Finally, on a separate track, Trump ordered an end to the “de minimis” duty exemption for low-value packages from China, closing a loophole that Chinese e-commerce firms had used to avoid tariffs by direct shipping to consumers.
In sum, the Reciprocal Tariff Policy establishes a two-tier tariff system: a uniform 10% tariff on all countries, and a higher tariff schedule for specific partners calibrated to what Trump officials view as reciprocity adjustments. The adjustments account not only for tariff differentials but also for non-tariff barriers and even macroeconomic policies. As stated, the higher rates aim to “capture” advantages other countries gain via practices like currency manipulation, lax labor and environmental laws, or burdensome regulations that exclude U.S. products.
In other words, the administration is using tariffs as a blunt instrument to offset a wide range of foreign policies it considers unfair. It is worth noting how extraordinary this is: the U.S. has effectively abandoned the WTO’s MFN norm (equal tariffs for all) in favor of bespoke rates by country – a throwback to pre-1940s trade relations.
Comparing Past and Present: Tariffs Then vs. Now
Trump’s reciprocal tariff gambit invites comparison to earlier high-tariff eras – but there are important differences. When the U.S. relied on tariffs historically, it was a rising industrial economy with large trade surpluses, abundant domestic raw materials, and a relatively self-contained market. Tariffs in those days could protect growing industries without severely choking off consumers, partly because Americans had fewer import-dependent consumption habits. Moreover, foreign retaliation was limited by the fact that the U.S. wasn’t as deeply enmeshed in global supply chains.
Today’s context is fundamentally different. The U.S. is a services-led, consumption-driven economy, deeply integrated into global production networks and heavily reliant on imports for consumer goods and industrial inputs. Unlike the late 19th century, when tariff protection coincided with robust economic growth, the U.S. now runs chronic trade deficits, importing far more than it exports. Those deficits are financed by foreign capital, making the U.S. a debtor nation. This means U.S. spending (both government and household) exceeds output – a structural reality that tariffs alone may not cure. In economic terms, a trade deficit reflects an imbalance between domestic saving and investment. As the International Monetary Fund notes, “protectionist policies are unlikely to be of much use in improving the current account balance because there is no obvious connection between protectionism and savings or investment.”
In other words, unless the U.S. reduces its overall spending relative to income (or increases savings), slapping tariffs on imports might simply reshuffle which countries the U.S. buys from or alter prices, without fixing the underlying deficit issue. This macroeconomic perspective did not feature prominently in 19th-century debates but looms large today.
Another key distinction is the potential impact on prices and supply chains. Historically, high tariffs often led to higher consumer prices and even “currency chaos” as nations responded (for example, in the 1890s and 1930s, trade partners retaliated and sometimes devalued currencies). We already saw hints of this in the 2018-2019 trade war, when Trump’s first-term tariffs on washing machines, steel, etc., raised costs for American manufacturers and consumers. The new 2025 tariffs are far more sweeping – effectively a tax on nearly all imported goods – so the inflationary impact could be significant. Past U.S. tariff hikes (e.g. Smoot-Hawley) hit during deflationary times; in contrast, implementing a 10–30% cost increase on a wide range of imports today risks adding to inflation pressures, unless offset by currency adjustments or profit margin compression. U.S. companies dependent on imported components may face difficult cost increases or supply shortages in the short run, something less relevant in the more self-sufficient U.S. economy of 1900.
Historically, high-tariff America was building industries that did not exist domestically; today, tariffs are being applied on products that often are available from U.S. producers or allies, but via integrated global supply. For instance, imposing a 25% tariff on imported semiconductors or machinery now (if not exempted) could slow downstream U.S. industries that need those inputs – a complexity absent in 1890 when such global sourcing was minimal. Additionally, the U.S. in 2025 has legal obligations (trade agreements and WTO rules) that did not constrain 19th-century policymakers. While 19th-century tariffs were a sovereign decision, today’s are a breach of commitments – inviting legal challenges and eroding U.S. credibility in international institutions.
In short, comparing eras suggests caution: The U.S. once grew behind tariff walls when it was capitalizing on a vast internal market and foreign markets were smaller. Now, as a mature economy with different strengths (services, advanced tech) and dependencies, broad tariffs may yield very different results.
Conclusion
President Trump’s 2025 Reciprocal Tariff Policy represents a dramatic experiment in 21st-century trade policy – effectively jettisoning decades of U.S. commitment to multilateral free trade in favor of an aggressive bilateral balancing approach. Historically, the United States benefited from an open system it largely designed; returning to high tariffs recalls an earlier era under vastly changed conditions, and it carries significant risks. While the policy is intended to protect industries and restore fairness as the administration views it, the potential costs include alienating allies, inviting retaliation that harms U.S. exporters (notably farmers and aircraft makers), raising costs for consumers and downstream industries, and destabilizing the rules-based trading system that has governed global commerce since World War II.
Whether the reciprocal tariff strategy “succeeds” depends on one’s metrics. If success is judged by reduction in the trade deficit and a revival of certain factory jobs, there might be some movement in those indicators (for example, the trade deficit may fall if imports plunge).
Retaliation and economic pain tend to go hand in hand with trade wars. Ultimately, the effectiveness of Trump’s 2025 trade gambit will be judged by whether it leads to negotiated better deals (partners lowering their barriers) or whether it devolves into a tit-for-tat quagmire, like with China. If it’s the latter, the U.S. and global economy will bear a substantial cost. History suggests caution, as trade wars are easier to start than to stop.
The MFN principle means that a country cannot discriminate between its trading partners. If a WTO member grants a favorable trade condition (like lower tariffs or fewer trade barriers) to one country, it must extend the same favor to all other WTO members.